Federal Reserve Blinks, Eyes Interest Rate Cuts

Dr. Engelhardt: Economy Beholden to Fed Interest Rate Policy; Here's One Way Gold Could Reach $14,000+...


Mike Gleason Mike Gleason
Interview with: Dr. Lucas Engelhardt
February 22nd, 2019 Comments

Also listen and subscribe on:

Welcome to this week’s Market Wrap Podcast, I’m Mike Gleason.

Coming up we’ll hear from Dr. Lucas Engelhardt, associate professor of economics at Kent State University and well-known Austrian economist and regular guest lecturer at the Mises Institute.

Dr. Engelhardt enlightens us on some of the major flaws in our current monetary policy and the dangers and economic trouble it will eventually produce. He also discusses a couple of different ways we could reintroduce a gold standard to save us from what appears to be an inevitable economic catastrophe. Don’t miss a fascinating interview with Dr. Lucas Engelhardt, coming up after this week’s market update.

Investors got hit with new reports of economic sluggishness this week as the Federal Reserve vowed patience on interest rates.

On Wednesday the Federal Open Market Committee released details from its most recent policy meeting. Monetary planners backed off on a rate hike and gave a more dovish outlook for the rest of the year. Fed officials offered up the word “patient” to describe their approach to policy decisions.

They’ve been trying to normalize interest rates and pare down their $4 trillion balance sheet for a few years now, so nobody doubts their patience. However, there are doubts about their resolve to continue with additional rate hikes given the pressure on them from Washington and Wall Street to maintain easy money.

Fed chair Jerome Powell insists the central bank is above politics. But it’s impossible to separate political concerns from concerns over the economy.

Disappointing economic data continues to roll in. The Atlanta Federal Reserve cut its forecast for gross domestic product growth. The latest durable goods report came in weaker than expected. On the housing front, the National Association of Realtors reported existing home sales fell 1.2% in January to post a third straight month of declines. Consumer confidence is also beginning to slip.

All this raises the prospect that the Fed’s next interest rate move could be a cut rather than a hike. Former Fed chair Janet Yellen said a rate cut is possible if the economic growth outlook continues to contract.

The current president of the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, James Bullard, said Wednesday he thinks monetary policy is too tight. He would like to undo the last rate hike.

The Fed raised rates four times in 2018 up to a range of 2.25 to 2.5%. It wanted to get up to at least 3% ahead of the next recession so it would have ample room to cut. Unless the economic numbers start improving, though, it’s doubtful policymakers will have the stomach for further hikes.

Whether investors have the stomach to keep bidding up pricey stock market indexes remains to be seen. Lately they have shown some interest in precious metals.

Metals markets rallied strongly early this week before giving back some of their gains on Thursday. Gold ran up to the $1,350 level before encountering selling pressure there. As of this Friday recording the yellow metal checks in at $1,330 an ounce, up 0.7% on the week.

Turning to the white metals, silver shows a weekly gain of 1.2% to trade at $15.95 an ounce. Platinum showing some signs of life, up 4.2% this week to trade at $844. And finally, palladium continues to shine, hitting another new record high this week. The catalytic metal currently trades at $1,494 on the heels of a 3.3% weekly advance as of this Friday morning recording.

Well, gold continues to be at the center of controversy surrounding the rightful ownership of Venezuelan gold. As we reported previously, the Bank of England refused to return $1.2 billion in gold bullion it held on behalf of the Venezuelan government. Now Citibank is consulting with U.S. Treasury Department officials to determine what to do about a $1.1 billion gold swap contract with the embattled Maduro regime.

U.S. sanctions on Nicolas Maduro’s government prohibit companies from dealing in Venezuelan gold. U.S. backed opposition leader Juan Guaido wants Citi to safeguard the gold assets in question on behalf of the Venezuelan people until Maduro is ousted.

It’s remarkable how much trust Maduro’s government officials placed in global financial institutions, especially with their own gold reserves. Gold is supposed to serve as an ultimate, tangible form of money that doesn’t depend on foreign currency exchange rates or foreign banking counterparties.

A nation’s gold reserves must be able to be quickly deployed during a financial emergency. When that emergency came for Venezuela, much of its gold held outside its own borders became inaccessible.

To be sure, Maduro and his socialist regime brought the financial emergency upon themselves with their crazy policies. But an obvious lesson for investors is to not entrust precious metals holdings to the custodianship of any bank. Not even a bank safe-deposit box should be trusted.

In fact, some banks specifically prohibit various forms of money including gold coins from being stored in safe-deposit boxes. If you hold precious metals in a bank safe-deposit box, you run the risk of them being subject to government edicts covering banks. And you run the risk of the bank running into financial trouble and going bust, potentially making your holdings inaccessible.

One of your main objectives in owning physical bullion should be to have some significant portion of your wealth held entirely outside the banking and brokerage systems. Don’t defeat that objective by converting your precious metals into vulnerable financial products.

Well now, without further delay, let’s get right to this week’s exclusive interview.

Dr. Lucas Engelhardt

Mike Gleason: It is my privilege now to welcome in Dr. Lucas Engelhardt associate professor of economics at Kent State University. Dr. Engelhardt is an Austrian economist who has been a guest lecturer at the Mises Institute and in his teaching specializes in macro-economics in the examination of the business cycle, and it's certainly a real pleasure to have him on with us today. Lucas, thanks so much for taking the time and welcome.

Dr. Lucas Engelhardt: Well thank you for having me on.

Mike Gleason: Well, I'm excited to have you on today because there is a lot to discuss with you. For starters I think a good place to begin is the business cycle. Now, but before we get into the misunderstandings that the Keynesians seems to have about this, explain the business cycle if you would and why it's important in order to have a proper understanding of monetary policy.

Dr. Lucas Engelhardt: Sure. Now, as you mentioned, I come from the Austrian economic framework. And Austrian economics describes the business cycle as the consequence of manipulations happening in the money supply, specifically in credit markets. So starting from that point, so how the business cycle happens is that we have somebody in the banking system. We know in modern America it would be the Federal Reserve is generally responsible for this. Decides to push down interest rates, normally to stimulate the economy.

Austrians, we definitely do not deny that this actually does work for a while. That the lower interest rate does actually encourage investment, especially in very long structures of production. The types of things that won't pay off maybe for five, 10, or even more years. We see lots of research and development, lots of construction, these types of things happening when interest rates get pushed down.

The problem is that the way that the Fed pushes interest rates down, as I suspect most of your listeners know, is by adding additional money into the economy through the banking system. Eventually this money gets out into the economy and prices start going up. You have more money, the money loses value, the flip side of that is that prices are higher. It takes more money to buy anything.

Now, there are a couple ways this can go. The central bank could just ignore this fact and continue with the low interest rate policy, just pumping out more and more money to the point where the money is worthless. We see that happen right throughout history, and we see that happening today in places like Venezuela. Now, what the Fed has done historically most of the time is get nervous about this rise in prices and start tamping back on the increase in the money supply. Of course, as soon as they do that interest rates go up. Once interest rates go up, all these investments that looked great when interest rates were low, that research and development, building new houses and what have you, stop looking as good.

So, we see all of these areas that expanded then start contracting, and that's where we see the bust of the business cycle come in. We see there it's really all centered on what the Federal Reserve in modern America is doing in interest rates.

Mike Gleason: Now, you come at things from an Austrian viewpoint as you mentioned. I'm curious if sometimes you feel like a lone wolf in the wilderness, because nearly everyone in the mainstream financial world and among the central bankers and central planners throughout the globe seems to have that Keynesian mindset where government and a tight management of monetary policy is the answer to every economic problem. So, why is it dangerous in your view, expand the point if you would about a centrally planned economy instead of letting the free market forces dictate things. What are they so afraid of?

Dr. Lucas Engelhardt: Yeah, that's a funny question. I think, like to me, a lot of the error that's out there is because somewhere along the lines economists, and I think people more generally have gotten into their mind that money is somehow totally different from other goods. You ask almost any economist out there, for most goods, things like shoes and shirts and whatever, they're generally perfectly happy to have the government stay out and let the market be in charge of deciding what kinds of shoes are being produced for whom and what have you.

But, then money suddenly, even people who are relatively free market, like Milton Friedman for example, they feel like money's different in some way and the government needs to have more of a role there. I'm not entirely sure where that comes from to be perfectly honest. It's this odd inconsistency. But, in terms of the danger of that, I think we already described the business cycle is something we see precisely because we've put the central bank in charge of the money supply, and them interacting with the credit markets.

Whereas, we wouldn't see the same type of process play out if instead we had private money producers using some kind of commodity, probably something like gold or silver historically, just producing as people want the good. Like we do with anything else. We don't really find that to be necessarily problematic.

Honestly, I don't have any great explanation for why most of my profession does seem to have this weird hang up when it comes to having markets in money.

Mike Gleason: Obviously, a lot of mal-investment does happen as a result of low interest rate policy. As you mentioned, as interest rates rise that no longer is a good way to use funds, and then the whole thing sort of implodes. Talk about that a little bit more if you would, and why it is that an economy really does need to go through these contractive periods, that it doesn't seem like central planners really want to allow nowadays.

Dr. Lucas Engelhardt: I think probably the best explanation of it I've seen of this comes from Ludwig Von Mises. The analogy that he gives is the analogy of the home builder. So you imagine that we have this home builders building this neighborhood, and they've been reported to them that there are a certain number of bricks available for them to use.

So, they then begin laying foundations and building these various houses in this neighborhood. But, then they discover part way through that there are not as many bricks available as was believed. The question is then, what are the lessons we can pull out of this?

First, the earlier we learn that the better. So, if we've just laid the foundations and then we find out we don't have as many bricks as we thought, we can salvage most of what we've done. On the other hand, if we get to the point where we've already built the first floor of every single house and then we find out we're running out of bricks, that totally changes our plans in a way that's much more destructive. So, the earlier we learn the better.

Also, it tells us that the closer we were to right at the beginning the better. The less error there was in that initial report is better. So, what in the world does this have to do with business cycles?

So then, we back up and think about in a free market economy where we don't have manipulation of interest rates, what does the interest rate mean? Well, the interest rate then would come out of peoples willingness to save for the future. If you're willing to save a lot then interest rates are going to generally be fairly low. We don't have to convince people to save if they're already will to. On the other hand, if people are not willing to save very much, then interest rates will generally be very high.

This in turn means that those low interest rates are a signal to investors that they can undertake these long processes of production. They can start doing things like mining, construction, research and development. These people are willing to save up for that eventual product that will come far in the future.

On the other hand, high interest rates send exactly the opposite signal. People are not willing to save for the far future, and that signals to investors that they won't have the resources to complete these very long investment products. So, that's where the signaling role of interest rates is absolutely key in getting the economy to work properly. And that's something that we lose when we have something like the Federal Reserve in charge of determining what interest rates are going to be.

The more they manipulate interest rates; the worse things are going to be. So, the more they try to keep interest rates really, really low in order to try to stimulate the economy, the longer we're going thinking we have more bricks than we do. Or, believing that people are willing to save up for the future when they're not actually willing to do that, and the further we get in more and more of these investments that aren't going to pay off.

So, the sooner we can hit that point where we've realized the error we have made, the smaller the error actually is. I think that's the way it is with most things in life. The earlier we catch ourselves making a mistake, the better off we are because we can fix it before things have gotten too bad.

Mike Gleason: Very well put. Talk about this idea of inflation targeting that the Federal Reserve seems to be holding so dear. This magic number of two percent inflation that they so desperately want to achieve. Talk about the flaws in that practice and then maybe also discuss some of the dangers of inflation in general, which is really just a hidden tax on the citizens at the end of the day, isn't it?

Dr. Lucas Engelhardt: Oh yeah. So, inflation targeting, the idea is, and this is actually something, it's kind of an interesting idea. The first place I know that implemented this was New Zealand a few years ago, where they were having this problem where they had very high rates of price inflation. So, they decided what they were going to decrease inflation to some more reasonable level. Something like three percent. I don't remember the exact number they were going.

They found that they actually managed to pull it off. Prices fell, they didn't have a horrible recession as would often be the case if you tried to pull this off some other way, because people seemed to believe them. So, after this example from New Zealand, it seems to have caught on as this great idea that everybody needs to do.

What's then the problem with this, it seemed to work at least that time. Well, to me the fundamental problem is how do we measure the thing? So, we know that here that the most common measure that we would use in the U.S. is the Consumer Price Index. We have this basket of goods, right, things we think normal people would buy, and we look at how the cost of this basket changes over time.

Now, there are a number of errors that can show up in this index, which really anybody who takes the first semester of macroeconomics gets taught the weaknesses. It doesn't matter who's teaching it, you learn the weaknesses of this particular index. Things like it totally ignores relative price changes.

So, if say both apples and oranges are in this consumer basket, and apples go up in price, but oranges drop, that is not taken into account when we're calculating the cost of the basket in the future… despite the fact that I would guess that basically most normal people if apples are getting more expensive and oranges are getting cheaper, are going to change what they buy. So, we get things like that. Or people will change where they shop based on what prices are doing. So, if prices are going up a lot in specialty stores they start shopping more at big box stores, or vice versa.

So, we can see all of these little changes at the micro level that people will actually make in their lives, we just don't catch. So, the CPI is the most common way we would measure this, but it's not the only one. There are other measures of inflation out there, and all of them have various weaknesses attached to them.

Then, the question is if we know that all of our measures are going to be mis-stating the thing that we're actually trying to shoot for in some way or another, and it's not always predictable which direction or how much, then what's really the point in having a target for this thing? We won't actually ever know if we've hit it. So, that to me is a rather significant problem.

Another issue is, it feels like an abusive language to me. Because, if you read the act that... I'm trying to remember the name of the most recent one that influences the Federal Reserve’s targets, I forget exactly what it was called. But, they're supposed to aim for price stability, and bizarrely this means prices increase on the average two percent per year.

I don't know about you, but if my height increased by two percent two year, I would not consider it to be stable. I'd say that I was actually growing. Similarly I'd say with prices if they're going up two percent per year, that's not stability that's actually an increase in prices.

Mike Gleason: Right, the opposite of stability.

Dr. Lucas Engelhardt: Right, exactly. Okay, maybe they're not flying all over the place unpredictably, but it's still not stable. But, in any case, what does this do even if it is predictable? Well, this does change people’s behavior. If for example we have prices are increasing overtime, that changes the way we decide to hold money versus invest in riskier financial assets, for example.

Where we know that if we're under a much more stable currency, we know that over the long run the gold standard was very stable. If you look at prices when you try to compile what these price indices might look like in 1650 and you compare that to 1900, the basket of goods basically costs the same amount. Over the course of a 250 year period we saw very little change in terms of an overall trend. What that means then is that holding money itself is not necessarily a terrible investment in that type of society.

That makes it very easy for people who are relatively low income, actually. You don't have to know a lot about stocks, you don't have to know a lot about how financial markets work. You just hold onto your gold coins until you want to use them and that's going to work pretty well for most people. But then, when you have a system like ours where every single year, if the Fed accomplishes its goal, all the money you have has just lost two percent of its value. You don't want to do that.

You have to start searching out other things that are actually going to pay you something. And we know that with interest rates being what they are right now, just sticking the money into a savings account, being a relatively safe, easy thing to do, well that's not going to help at all. I know my savings account I believe pays .01%, which they may as well just round that down to zero. So, you have to start searching out things that are riskier, at which point knowledge about financial markets becomes much more important.

It turns out, I would suggest inflation, and I'm not the only one suggesting this, inflation does play a big role in driving things like inequality. It makes it much more difficult relatively for those with lower incomes than for those with higher incomes. Precisely because it's taken away all of these relatively easy, relatively stable sorts of investments that were available under more stable currency.

Mike Gleason: Yeah, it certainly does create a bigger divide. The wage earner seems to be the one that is most harmed by this inflationary policy, for sure. Now, the Austrians talk a lot about the gold standard, you referenced that in your previous answer. It's a good way to keep politicians in check, keeping government debt in check. So, in a perfect world, how would a gold standard be reintroduced at this point, Lucas, and what problems do you believe it would correct, or would some other type of monetary reform be better to solve our issues for instance?

Dr. Lucas Engelhardt: Yeah, that's kind of a tricky question of, “Okay, if we have this system we like how do we possibly get there?” Well, there are a couple different plans that some of the big name Austrian economists have come up with to try to move us back towards say a gold based currency. Ludwig Von Mises, his plan was, the first step is we stop issuing additional paper dollars. Then, whenever the price of gold stabilizes, we just declare that that is going to be the parity between dollars and gold, and then we have a conversion agency that will guarantee conversion in either direction from these.

So, say that the price of gold stabilizes at, I don't know, $2,500 an ounce. In that case, you can go to this conversion agency, if you have $2,500 they guarantee providing you with an ounce of gold. If you provide them with an ounce of gold, they guarantee providing you with $2,500. So, in that way, the paper currency we're all using now would become as good as gold again, because it would in fact be backed by gold.

He also suggests eliminating any larger bills, which at the time he was writing this was several decades ago, he considered a large bill to be five dollars and up… which tells you something about what prices have done over the past few decades if that's a large bill.

He said we need to eliminate all these large bills and instead use gold coins. Get people used to the idea that gold is in fact money, and so we have this psychological connection with the metal itself.

So, I did some math just to find out, say if we had a dime that was made of gold how much that would be worth. Turns out, it would be about $120 roughly, right, would be a gold dime. Which, makes sense looking at gold prices. One ounce of gold is around $1,200, a dime is about a 10th of an ounce of gold.

Mike Gleason: Yeah, we often talk about that in the 10th ounce of gold products that we sell…. very close in size to a dime.

Dr. Lucas Engelhardt: Right. Yeah, so that was Mises's idea of how we could reconnect, the money we use now with gold. One thing I really like about Mises's plan, is Mises was very aware of some of the difficulties that can show up with the transitions. So, you can see where the plan is designed to not necessarily be that disruptive. We're just stopping one thing we're doing, that is the printing of additional paper dollars, we're letting the market stabilize, and then reacting to what the market does.

Another plan came from Murray Rothbard, his plan I think was, in my mind, a little bit more radical. What he suggested is that the Federal Reserve does have claim to some gold holdings, so what they could do is take all of the money supply using some measure of the money supply, pick M1, M2, whatever, and then basically do the division.

So, we know that there are however many trillion dollars nowadays of M2. There are this many ounces of gold that the fed has claim to, so there's this many dollars per ounce of gold, that's the price of gold. And then, if everybody rushes to hand in their paper dollars we don't have any problem, which could be a problem potentially under Mises's plan. When I did the math there, it turns out if we tried to back all of M2, which would be all of the paper currency, checking accounts, savings accounts, small time deposits like small certificates of deposit would be included in there as well, and money market mutual funds held by individuals… all of those would be included in that.

If we backed all of that money by gold, that would make the price of gold $54,000 per ounce. Which is a bit different from what we're currently seeing in the market.

Mike Gleason: Yeah, just a little bit. Just a little bit higher.

Dr. Lucas Engelhardt: Yeah, a touch. A touch. Now, if we wanted to do something more narrow, like M1 would basically just be paper currency plus our checking accounts, that would still be looking at $14,000 per ounce, would be required to just back that. So, we're looking at a rather drastic change, and I suspect that would very much change things like how much are we exploring for new gold, how much are we putting into gold mining, that kind of thing. I suspect we'd see significant economic changes there. But, that would be a one-time adjustment, really.

Mike Gleason: Yeah, it certainly would be something that could finally have an effect on the out of control government spending, it just doesn't matter who's in power, it just continues to get bigger and bigger all the time.

Switching gears here a bit, and as we begin to wrap up here, right now most of America is basking in the economic recovery. Their stock portfolios are moving higher and home values are rising. Unemployment is low, at least in the way the Bureau of Labor Statistics measures it. The 2008 financial crisis is a pretty distant memory now, but in our way of thinking of at least, the fundamental problems, things like too much debt and too much government have not been solved. In fact, they are compounding and it is likely not to end well. But, give us your assessment on this recovery, and can we get a few more years of expansion here?

Dr. Lucas Engelhardt: I feel like a few more years is asking quite a bit. The big thing that I look at, and really, this is a strange thing, while as an Austrian I'm a strange creature, yet many of the things I look at are things that other economists would look at all the time. I pay a lot of attention to the yield curve.

It turns out there are good Austrian reasons that we should pay attention the yield curve, and the yield curve has gotten extremely flat, which is generally not a good sign. Especially if the yield curve inverts, so that short term interest rates are higher than long term. That indicates that we should probably have a recession, usually starting within about a year from that point.

We've not seen it invert yet, but we're looking really, really flat. And the Fed has indicated that they're going to be pushing up interest rates, and we know that they have the most influence over short term rates. So, I would not be surprised that if say within the next two years we see some kind of recession start.

There are certain things they can try to do to delay that. Not so much the Fed – the Fed basically has interest rates, which is what they're playing with – but we could see, say, I don't know, Congress try to pass another tax cut or something like, which could potentially offset this for a bit. I don't really see that we're going to be able to put it off for long, especially given that we just had this tax cut, I don't know that we can afford to have another one. We see government debt piling up as it is.

Mike Gleason: Yeah, they always seem to want to cut taxes, which of course is a good thing and we're all for that, but it never seems to be accompanied by cuts in government spending.

Dr. Lucas Engelhardt: Right, exactly. It's very much like if I decided, you know, I'll work less and earn less money but I'm going to keep living my life as it is. You can't do that forever. Eventually you're going to have to adjust to get these things to line up, and that's going to be very painful when it happens. Especially with how out of alignment we see between our revenue and our spending. We're going to have to see big cuts in spending, or a big tax bite coming to bring that back into line.

Like, right now, at least from what I've seen, it seems like we're trying to cover up most of that difference by printing money and if the Fed is increasing interest rates, they're basically signaling they're not willing to continue printing money to do this, so interest rates are on their way up.

And go back to the story we told at the beginning, interest rates being on the way up is what starts making those investments that looked good a couple years ago when interest rates were lower, they're going to start looking bad and we see things turn for the worse.

Mike Gleason: Yeah, very well summarized there, and I think that kind of crystallizes the whole situation there with interest rates and the end of the speculative period, and the mal-investment that’s been driving this economy for quite a while. Obviously, we have a very debt driven economy, cheap money, and that appears to be coming to an end. And it's going to get very interesting.

I would like to consider this conversation with you down the line, a lot of stuff we didn't actually get to today, but I did really enjoy. Thanks for coming on, we appreciate you sharing your insights, and I hope we can speak with you down the road. Best of luck to you in influencing those young minds for good. We wish you well, and take care. Thanks for coming on.

Dr. Lucas Engelhardt: Yeah, yeah, thank you very much and thanks for having me.

Mike Gleason: Well, that will do it for this week. Thanks again to Dr. Lucas Engelhardt, associate professor of economics at Kent State University.

Be sure to check back here next Friday for our next Weekly Market Wrap Podcast, until then, this has been Mike Gleeson with Money Metals Exchange, thanks for listening, and have a great weekend everybody.

Mike Gleason

About the Author:

Mike Gleason is a Director with Money Metals Exchange, a precious metals dealer recently named "Best in the USA" by an independent global ratings group. Gleason is a hard money advocate and a strong proponent of personal liberty, limited government and the Austrian School of Economics. A graduate of the University of Florida, Gleason has extensive experience in management, sales and logistics as well as precious metals investing. He also puts his longtime broadcasting background to good use, hosting a weekly precious metals podcast since 2011, a program listened to by tens of thousands each week.